Related Questions
- I Need Help With The Coding/Syntax Aspects Of A Modeling Project In Matlab
- College Java Project - Javafx Assignment
- Doing Python Homework Assignment
- Advanced Algorithm Analysis For Efficient Computing In Data Science- Help With My Dissertation Proposal
- Research And Write A Paper On Programming Languages
- Api Programming Project: Help Retrieve Demographic Data From A Web Server In Matlab
- Print Air_Temperature With 1 Decimal Point Followed By C. Sample Output With Input: 36.4158102 36.4C
- Matlab Assignment
- Matlab, Non Linear Optimization Project
- Code For Statistical Mechanics
- I Need To Hire Someone To Take The Alteryx Core Certification Exam For Me
- Sql Questions
- Matlab Project
- I Am Needing Tutoring In Assembly Language
- What Is Php And How Do I Use It?
Popular Services
- Coursework writing help
- Term paper writing help
- Writing Help
- Paper Writing Help
- Research paper help
- Thesis Help
- Dissertation Help
- Case study writing service
- Capstone Project Writing Help
- Lab report Writing
- Take my online class
- Take my online exam
- Do my test for me
- Do my homework for me
- Do my math homework for me
- Online Assignment Help
- Do my assignment for me
- Essay Writing Help
- Write my college essay
- Write my essay for me
Post your project now for free and watch professional homework help answers experts outbid each other in just a few minutes.
Question: R Studio Multiple Regressions Hw Help
Asked
Modified
Viewed
45
I only need the coding portion of this assignment (the R script). The data required is the CountryData and the CorruptionNorm. This is required to be done in R studio and uses packages like tidyverse to make graphs better looking. Everything for the assignment is provided, thank you.
More Instructions
1020
[ Journal of Political Economy, 2007, vol. 115, no. 6]
� 2007 by The University of Chicago. All rights reserved. 0022-3808/2007/11506-0002$10.00
Corruption, Norms, and Legal Enforcement:
Evidence from Diplomatic Parking Tickets
Raymond Fisman
Columbia University and National Bureau of Economic Research
Edward Miguel
University of California, Berkeley and National Bureau of Economic Research
We study cultural norms and legal enforcement in controlling cor-
ruption by analyzing the parking behavior of United Nations officials
in Manhattan. Until 2002, diplomatic immunity protected UN dip-
lomats from parking enforcement actions, so diplomats’ actions were
constrained by cultural norms alone. We find a strong effect of cor-
ruption norms: diplomats from high-corruption countries (on the
basis of existing survey-based indices) accumulated significantly more
unpaid parking violations. In 2002, enforcement authorities acquired
the right to confiscate diplomatic license plates of violators. Unpaid
violations dropped sharply in response. Cultural norms and (partic-
ularly in this context) legal enforcement are both important deter-
minants of corruption.
We thank Stefano Dellvigna, Seema Jayachandran, Dean Yang, Luigi Zingales, and sem-
inar participants at the Harvard Development Economics Lunch, Harvard Behavioral
Economics Seminar, Harvard Kennedy School of Government, Harvard Political Economy
discussion group, University of Michigan, London School of Economics, University of
Southern California, Stockholm University, University of California, Berkeley, Northwest-
ern University, University of Hawaii, Syracuse University, Harvard Business School, World
Bank, University of Toronto, two anonymous referees, and Steve Levitt for helpful sug-
gestions. Daniel Hartley, Adam Sacarny, and Sarath Sanga provided superb research as-
sistance. We thank Gillian Sorensen for helpful discussions. We are especially grateful to
the New York City Department of Finance for providing us with data on parking violations
and National Public Radio for alerting us to the existence of these data. All errors are
our own.
corruption, norms, and legal enforcement 1021
I. Introduction
The underlying causes of corruption remain poorly understood and
widely debated. Yet the study of corruption beyond the realm of opinion
surveys is still in its infancy, and there is little firm evidence relating
corruption to real-world causal factors. Notably, both social norms and
legal enforcement are often mentioned as primary contributors to cor-
ruption in both the academic literature and the popular press, yet there
is no evidence beyond the most casual of cross-country empirics.1
Distinguishing between the effects of social norms and legal enforce-
ment is confounded by problems of identification: societies that collec-
tively place less importance on rooting out corruption, and thus have
weak anticorruption social norms, may simultaneously have less legal
enforcement. Understanding the relative importance of these potential
causes of corruption is of central importance in reforming public in-
stitutions to improve governance and in the current debate in foreign
aid policy. The World Bank emphasizes effectiveness of legal enforce-
ment, but social reformers have highlighted the importance of changing
civic norms in anticorruption efforts.2
We develop an empirical approach for evaluating the role of both
social norms and legal enforcement in corruption by studying parking
violations among United Nations diplomats living in New York City.
Mission personnel and their families benefit from diplomatic immunity,
a privilege that allowed them to avoid paying parking fines prior to
November 2002. The act of parking illegally fits well with a standard
definition of corruption, that is, “the abuse of entrusted power for pri-
vate gain,”3 suggesting that the comparison of parking violations by
diplomats from different societies serves as a plausible measure of the
extent of corruption social norms or a corruption “culture.”
This setting has a number of advantages for studying corruption
norms. Most important, our approach avoids the problem of differential
legal enforcement levels across countries and more generally strips out
enforcement effects prior to the New York City government’s enforce-
1 See Lambsdorff (2006) for an overview of findings on the determinants of corruption
based on cross-country comparisons. Witzel (2005) provides one of many discussions on
the topic in the popular press. The effects of legal enforcement on crime in general have
been much examined theoretically, beginning with Becker (1968). Theories of norms and
corruption are presented in Mauro (2004), which discusses models of multiple equilibria
in corruption levels that could be interpreted as capturing corruption culture, and in
Tirole (1996), which develops a model of bureaucratic collective reputation that also
implies persistent corruption.
2 One successful anticorruption reformer who focused on changing norms as an element
of reform, and who is well cited in the international media, is Antanas Mockus, the former
mayor of Bogotá, Colombia (Rockwell 2004).
3 This is the definition used by the leading anticorruption organization Transparency
International (see http://ww1.transparency.org/about_ti/mission.html).
1022 journal of political economy
ment actions of November 2002, since there was essentially no enforce-
ment of diplomats’ parking violations before this time. We thus interpret
diplomats’ behavior as reflecting their underlying propensity to break
rules for private gain when enforcement is not a consideration. Dip-
lomats to UN missions are also a relatively homogeneous group, selected
for similar official duties in New York. Additionally, because UN missions
are overwhelmingly colocated in Midtown Manhattan—87 percent of
missions are located within 1 mile of the UN complex—we avoid many
concerns of unobserved differences in parking availability across geo-
graphic settings.
This approach allows us to construct a “revealed preference” measure
of corruption among government officials across 149 countries, based
on real rule breaking in parking.4 Corruption levels, particularly across
countries, have proved challenging to measure objectively because of
the illicit nature of corrupt activities. In our main empirical results, we
find that this parking violation corruption measure is strongly positively
correlated with other (survey-based) country corruption measures and
that this relationship is robust to conditioning on region fixed effects,
country income, and a wide range of other controls, including govern-
ment employee salary measures. This suggests that home country cor-
ruption norms are an important predictor of propensity to behave cor-
ruptly among diplomats: those from low-corruption countries (e.g.,
Norway) behave remarkably well even in situations in which there are
no legal consequences, whereas those from high-corruption countries
(e.g., Nigeria) commit many violations. It also goes somewhat against
the predictions of standard economic models of crime in situations of
zero legal enforcement (e.g., Becker 1968), which would predict high
rates of parking violations among all diplomats in the absence of
enforcement.
The natural experiment of New York City diplomatic parking privi-
leges also allows for a direct comparison of the effects of norms versus
enforcement by exploiting a sharp increase in the legal punishment for
parking violations. Starting in November 2002, New York City began
stripping the official diplomatic license plates from vehicles that accu-
mulated more than three unpaid parking violations. This credible in-
crease in enforcement—the city government made examples of 30 coun-
tries by having their vehicles’ plates stripped in October 20025—led to
immediate and massive declines of approximately 98 percent in parking
violations (see fig. 1 below). Thus, cultural norms matter for crime, but
so does enforcement, a finding that resonates with the work of Becker
4 In this sense, our corruption measure is conceptually similar to the Economist
magazine’s “Big Mac Index” as a measure of country purchasing power parity.
5 Refer to Fries (2002) for an example of media coverage.
corruption, norms, and legal enforcement 1023
(1968), Levitt (1997, 2004), Di Tella and Schargrodsky (2003), and
others on the responsiveness of crime to punishment. In our setting,
the impact of legal enforcement appears larger than the effects of var-
iation in cultural norms across countries.
The main theoretical implication of these empirical patterns, taken
together, is that both cultural norms and legal enforcement play key
roles in government officials’ corruption decisions. They suggest that
both factors should be taken seriously in debates about the causes of
corruption and the policy measures to combat it.
Since the parking violations data exist at the individual level for all
UN mission diplomats present in New York City (numbering roughly
1,700 at the start of our study period), we can examine how individual
behavior evolves over time. For diplomats from high-corruption coun-
tries of origin, a model of convergence to U.S. corruption norms would
(presumably) predict a decline in the rate of parking violations over
time, as tenure in the United States increases. By contrast, a model of
convergence to the “zero-enforcement” norm discussed above would
imply an increase in violations over time, particularly for officials from
low-corruption countries. We find evidence that the frequency of vio-
lations increases with tenure in New York City and that these increases
are particularly large for diplomats from low-corruption countries, sug-
gesting that there is partial convergence to the zero-enforcement norm
over time.
Beyond contributing to the large literature in economics on the de-
terminants of legal compliance, our work is part of a growing body of
research on the importance of cultural background in explaining in-
dividual behavior. Much of this work compares the outcomes and actions
of immigrant groups from different countries. For example, Borjas
(2000) finds that home country attributes are predictive of immigrants’
economic achievement. In the social domain, Fernandez and Fogli
(2006) show that fertility rates among Americans are correlated with
fertility in their countries of ancestry. In work also related to ours, Ichino
and Maggi (2000) study absenteeism and misconduct of employees at
an Italian bank and find that region of origin within Italy predicts
shirking.
We also seek to contribute to the growing empirical literature on
corruption specifically. Other recent empirical research emphasizes the
importance of developing corruption measures based on real-world de-
cisions rather than survey responses; see Reinikka and Svensson (2004)
and Olken (2006) for discussions. This article is the first to our knowl-
edge to develop a revealed preference measure of corruption that is
comparable across countries. Finally, the importance of norm compli-
ance and nonselfish behavior has been documented in the laboratory
1024 journal of political economy
(see, e.g., Ledyard 1995), and more recently Levitt (2006) provides
evidence on norms of nonselfish behavior in the field.
The rest of the article proceeds as follows: Section II describes the
diplomatic parking situation in New York City and the violations data,
Section III discusses the rest of the data set, Section IV contains the
empirical results, and Section V presents conclusions.
II. Diplomatic Parking Violations in New York City
Diplomatic representatives to the United Nations and their families are
given immunity from prosecution or lawsuits in the United States. The
original intent of these laws was to protect diplomats from mistreatment
abroad, especially in countries not on friendly terms with the home
country.6 However, these days diplomatic immunity is more commonly
viewed as the “best free parking pass in town” (BBC News 1998). Dip-
lomatic vehicles in New York possess license plates tagged with the letter
D, which signals diplomatic status.7 While these vehicles may be ticketed,
the car’s registrant is shielded from any punishment for nonpayment
of the ticket. Thus one immediate implication of diplomatic immunity—
not just in New York, but also in most other capitals (e.g., London [BBC
News 1998], Paris [Agence Presse–France 2005], and Seoul [Korea Times
1999])—has been that it allows diplomats to park illegally but never
suffer the threat of legal punishment, leaving a “paper trail” of the illegal
acts (see http://www.state.gov/m/ds/immunities/c9127.htm). To illus-
trate the magnitude of the problem, between November 1997 and the
end of 2002 in New York City, diplomats accumulated over 150,000
unpaid parking tickets, resulting in outstanding fines of more than $18
million.
The New York City parking violations data are at the level of the
individual unpaid violation.8 Drivers have 30 days to pay a ticket before
it goes into default, at which point an additional penalty is levied (gen-
erally 110 percent of the initial fine). Diplomats then receive an addi-
tional 70 days to pay the ticket plus this penalty before it is recorded
in our data set as an unpaid violation in default. The information on
each violation includes the license plate number; the name and country
of origin of the car’s registrant; the date, time, and location of the
6 While the origins of diplomatic protection date back many centuries, the current
incarnation is found in the 1961 Vienna Convention on Diplomatic Relations. See
http://www.un.int/usa/host_dip.htm for the full text.
7 Note that while the vehicle’s diplomatic status is revealed by the license plate, the
country codes denoting particular countries are unrelated to country names; e.g., the
code (at the start of the plate number) for Mozambique is QS and the code for Nigeria
is JF.
8 We gratefully acknowledge the New York City Department of Finance, in particular
Sam Miller and Gerald Koszner, for compiling these data.
corruption, norms, and legal enforcement 1025
violation; the fine and penalty levied; and the amount paid (if any).
The most common violation in our data was parking in a No Standing—
Loading Zone (43 percent of violations), which is typically parking in
someone else’s driveway or business entrance. The remainder were
spread across a range of violation types that imply varying degrees of
social harm:9 fines for expired meters accounted for 6 percent of the
total, double-parking 5 percent, and parking in front of a fire hydrant
7 percent, for instance. Also note that in 20 percent of violations the
registrant is the mission itself, signifying an official rather than personal
vehicle. While the majority of violations are located within a mile of
either the country’s UN mission or the UN complex, many are com-
mitted in other parts of the city. We return to the issue of violation
location below. The total period of coverage in our data set is November
24, 1997, to November 21, 2005. (Refer to the Data Appendix for more
on the data set.)
A crucial change in legal enforcement took place in October 2002,
when the State Department gave New York City permission to revoke
the official diplomatic plates of vehicles with three or more outstanding
unpaid violations (Steinhauer 2002). In addition, the Clinton-Schumer
Amendment (named after the two New York senators), put in place at
the same time, allowed the city to petition the State Department to have
110 percent of the total amount due deducted from U.S. foreign aid
to the offending diplomats’ country, although this latter punishment
was never invoked in practice (Singleton 2004).
In constructing our data set, we generate separate measures of the
extent of unpaid violations for the pre-enforcement (November 1997–
October 2002) and postenforcement (November 2002–November 2005)
periods. In each case, we employ the total number of unpaid diplomatic
parking violations for a particular country. In order to control for base-
line mission size, we calculate the total number of UN permanent mis-
sion staff with diplomatic privileges using the UN Blue Book for May
1998. Published twice annually, the Blue Book lists all UN mission staff,
as well as their official titles. We additionally use UN Blue Books for
1997–2005 to track the UN tenure of individual diplomats. Fortunately,
the Blue Books generally use consistent spellings across editions, facil-
itating automated matching across time. In most cases, the spelling and
format were also consistent with the names in the parking violations
data; the algorithm automatically matched 61 percent of diplomats in
the violations database. The first Blue Book we use is from January 1997,
9 Almost all parking violations in the data set resulted in fines of US$55, making it
impossible to assess the extent of social damage by violations’ relative prices.
1026 journal of political economy
and we use this as our start date for calculating tenure at the United
Nations.10
We obtained data on the number of diplomatic license plates regis-
tered to each mission from the U.S. State Department’s Office of Foreign
Missions, and we use these data as a control variable in some specifi-
cations. Unfortunately, these data are available only for 2006, though
we were assured that the numbers are largely stable over time.11
Table 1 presents the annual number of violations per diplomat by
country during the pre-enforcement period (November 1997–October
2002) and the postenforcement period (November 2002–November
2005), along with the total number of diplomats in May 1998. Overall,
the basic pattern accords reasonably well with common perceptions of
corruption across countries. The worst parking violators—the 10 worst
(in order) are Kuwait, Egypt, Chad, Sudan, Bulgaria, Mozambique, Al-
bania, Angola, Senegal, and Pakistan—all rank poorly in cross-country
corruption rankings (described below), with the exception of Kuwait.
The raw correlation between the country corruption rankings and pre-
enforcement parking violations per diplomat is �0.18, and that between
the corruption ranking and postenforcement violations per capita is
�0.24. While many of the countries with zero violations accord well with
intuition (e.g., the Scandinavian countries, Canada, and Japan), there
are a number of surprises. Some of these are countries with very small
missions (e.g., Burkina Faso and the Central African Republic), and a
few others have high rates of parking violations but do pay off the fines
(these are Bahrain, Malaysia, Oman, and Turkey; we return to this issue
below). The smallest missions may plausibly have fewer violations since
each mission is given two legal parking spaces at the United Nations,
and this may suffice if the country has very few diplomats.
Figure 1 plots the total violations per month during November 1997–
November 2005. There are two clear declines in the number of viola-
tions. The first comes in September 2001, corresponding to the period
following the World Trade Center attack. The second and extremely
pronounced decline coincides with increased legal enforcement of dip-
lomatic parking violators.
10 That is, we cannot distinguish among arrival times pre-1997, and all individuals in-
cluded in the January 1997 Blue Book are coded as arriving in that month. As a robustness
check, we also limit the sample only to diplomats who were not yet present in New York
in the 1997 Blue Book (reducing the sample slightly), which allows us to more accurately
capture arrival date.
11 We thank Murray Smith of the U.S. Office of Foreign Services for these data and for
many useful conversations.
T
A
B
L
E
1
A
ve
ra
g
e
U
n
pa
id
A
n
n
u
al
N
ew
Yo
rk
C
it
y
Pa
rk
in
g
V
io
la
ti
o
n
s
pe
r
D
ip
lo
m
at
,N
o
ve
m
be
r
19
97
to
N
o
ve
m
be
r
20
05
Pa
rk
in
g
V
io
la
ti
on
s
R
an
k
C
ou
n
tr
y
N
am
e
V
io
la
ti
on
s
pe
r
D
ip
lo
m
at
,
Pr
e-
en
fo
rc
em
en
t
(1
1/
19
97
–1
1/
20
02
)
V
io
la
ti
on
s
pe
r
D
ip
lo
m
at
,
Po
st
en
fo
rc
em
en
t
(1
1/
20
02
–1
1/
20
05
)
U
N
M
is
si
on
D
ip
lo
m
at
s
in
19
98
C
or
ru
pt
io
n
In
de
x,
19
98
C
ou
n
tr
y
C
od
e
1
K
uw
ai
t
24
9.
4
.1
5
9
�
1.
07
K
W
T
2
E
gy
pt
14
1.
4
.3
3
24
.2
5
E
G
Y
3
C
h
ad
12
5.
9
.0
0
2
.8
4
T
C
D
4
Su
da
n
12
0.
6
.3
7
7
.7
5
SD
N
5
B
ul
ga
ri
a
11
9.
0
1.
64
6
.5
0
B
G
R
6
M
oz
am
bi
qu
e
11
2.
1
.0
7
5
.7
7
M
O
Z
7
A
lb
an
ia
85
.5
1.
85
3
.9
2
A
L
B
8
A
n
go
la
82
.7
1.
71
9
1.
05
A
G
O
9
Se
n
eg
al
80
.2
.2
1
11
.4
5
SE
N
10
Pa
ki
st
an
70
.3
1.
21
13
.7
6
PA
K
11
Iv
or
y
C
oa
st
68
.0
.4
6
10
.3
5
C
IV
12
Z
am
bi
a
61
.2
.1
5
9
.5
6
Z
M
B
13
M
or
oc
co
60
.8
.4
0
17
.1
0
M
A
R
14
E
th
io
pi
a
60
.4
.6
2
10
.2
5
E
T
H
15
N
ig
er
ia
59
.4
.4
4
25
1.
01
N
G
A
16
Sy
ri
a
53
.3
1.
36
12
.5
8
SY
R
17
B
en
in
50
.4
6.
50
8
.7
6
B
E
N
18
Z
im
ba
bw
e
46
.2
.8
6
14
.1
3
Z
W
E
19
C
am
er
oo
n
44
.1
2.
86
8
1.
11
C
M
R
20
M
on
te
n
eg
ro
an
d
Se
rb
ia
38
.5
.0
5
6
.9
7
YU
G
21
B
ah
ra
in
38
.2
.6
5
7
�
.4
1
B
H
R
22
B
ur
un
di
38
.2
.1
1
3
.8
0
B
D
I
1028
T
A
B
L
E
1
(C
on
tin
ue
d
)
Pa
rk
in
g
V
io
la
ti
on
s
R
an
k
C
ou
n
tr
y
N
am
e
V
io
la
ti
on
s
pe
r
D
ip
lo
m
at
,
Pr
e-
en
fo
rc
em
en
t
(1
1/
19
97
–1
1/
20
02
)
V
io
la
ti
on
s
pe
r
D
ip
lo
m
at
,
Po
st
en
fo
rc
em
en
t
(1
1/
20
02
–1
1/
20
05
)
U
N
M
is
si
on
D
ip
lo
m
at
s
in
19
98
C
or
ru
pt
io
n
In
de
x,
19
98
C
ou
n
tr
y
C
od
e
23
M
al
i
37
.9
.5
2
5
.5
8
M
L
I
24
In
do
n
es
ia
36
.5
.7
3
25
.9
5
ID
N
25
G
ui
n
ea
35
.2
.5
9
5
.5
7
G
N
B
26
B
os
n
ia
-H
er
ze
go
vi
n
a
34
.9
.1
1
6
.3
5
B
IH
27
So
ut
h
A
fr
ic
a
34
.5
.5
0
19
�
.4
2
Z
A
F
28
Sa
ud
i
A
ra
bi
a
34
.2
.5
2
12
�
.3
5
SA
U
29
B
an
gl
ad
es
h
33
.4
.2
9
8
.4
0
B
G
D
30
B
ra
zi
l
30
.3
.2
3
33
�
.1
0
B
R
A
31
Si
er
ra
L
eo
n
e
25
.9
1.
14
4
.7
2
SL
E
32
A
lg
er
ia
25
.6
1.
36
13
.7
0
D
Z
A
33
T
h
ai
la
n
d
24
.8
.9
8
13
.2
6
T
H
A
34
K
az
ak
h
st
an
21
.4
.2
5
9
.8
6
K
A
Z
35
M
au
ri
ti
us
20
.7
.0
8
4
�
.2
0
M
U
S
36
N
ig
er
20
.2
2.
51
3
.8
8
N
E
R
37
C
ze
ch
R
ep
ub
lic
19
.1
.0
0
7
�
.3
5
C
Z
E
38
L
es
ot
h
o
19
.1
.2
2
6
�
.0
3
L
SO
39
B
ot
sw
an
a
18
.7
.2
5
8
�
.5
3
B
W
A
40
B
h
ut
an
18
.6
.2
6
5
�
.4
6
B
T
N
41
Sr
i
L
an
ka
17
.4
.0
0
5
.2
4
L
K
A
42
C
h
ile
16
.7
.2
1
14
�
1.
20
C
H
L
43
Tu
n
is
ia
16
.7
.6
2
11
�
.1
1
T
U
N
44
N
ep
al
16
.7
.0
5
6
.5
9
N
PL
45
Ir
an
15
.9
.0
2
20
.6
3
IR
N
46
Fi
ji
15
.7
.3
3
3
�
.2
0
FJ
I
47
It
al
y
14
.8
.8
0
16
�
1.
00
IT
A
48
L
ib
er
ia
13
.7
.8
7
6
1.
44
L
B
R
1029
49
M
al
aw
i
13
.2
.0
5
6
.5
0
M
W
I
50
Pa
ra
gu
ay
13
.2
.5
5
6
.9
7
PR
Y
51
R
w
an
da
13
.1
1.
20
3
.5
5
R
W
A
52
U
kr
ai
n
e
13
.1
.7
0
14
.8
9
U
K
R
53
Sp
ai
n
12
.9
.5
2
15
�
1.
59
E
SP
54
Ph
ili
pp
in
es
11
.7
.0
8
20
.2
6
PH
L
55
G
h
an
a
11
.4
.1
6
10
.4
4
G
H
A
56
M
au
ri
ta
n
ia
11
.3
.2
6
5
.2
9
M
R
T
57
G
ui
n
ea
-B
is
sa
u
10
.9
1.
34
10
.8
2
G
IN
58
E
st
on
ia
10
.7
.4
4
3
�
.4
9
E
ST
59
M
on
go
lia
10
.3
.0
7
5
.2
8
M
N
G
60
A
rm
en
ia
10
.2
.1
6
4
.7
1
A
R
M
61
C
os
ta
R
ic
a
10
.2
.0
7
19
�
.7
1
C
R
I
62
C
om
or
os
10
.1
5.
23
3
.8
0
C
O
M
63
K
am
pu
ch
ea
(C
am
bo
di
a)
10
.0
.0
7
5
1.
27
K
H
M
64
To
go
10
.0
.9
8
5
.4
5
T
G
O
65
V
ie
tn
am
10
.0
.0
4
15
.6
0
V
N
M
66
G
eo
rg
ia
9.
8
.3
7
8
.6
4
G
E
O
67
C
h
in
a
(P
eo
pl
e’
s
R
ep
ub
lic
)
9.
6
.0
7
69
.1
4
C
H
N
68
Ye
m
en
9.
2
.0
8
8
.5
7
YE
M
69
Ve
n
ez
ue
la
9.
2
.1
0
16
.7
7
V
E
N
70
Po
rt
ug
al
8.
9
.7
8
16
�
1.
56
PR
T
71
U
zb
ek
is
ta
n
8.
9
.1
3
5
.9
8
U
Z
B
72
M
ad
ag
as
ca
r
8.
8
.5
7
8
.8
0
M
D
G
73
Ta
n
za
n
ia
8.
4
.7
4
8
.9
5
T
Z
A
74
L
ib
ya
8.
3
.3
3
9
.9
1
L
B
Y
75
K
en
ya
7.
8
.0
4
17
.9
2
K
E
N
76
C
on
go
(B
ra
zz
av
ill
e)
7.
8
.0
5
6
.9
9
C
O
G
77
C
ro
at
ia
6.
6
.1
8
9
.3
3
H
R
V
78
D
jib
ou
ti
6.
5
.0
0
3
.8
0
D
JI
79
Sl
ov
ak
R
ep
ub
lic
6.
5
.1
6
12
.0
8
SV
K
80
Z
ai
re
6.
4
.2
2
6
1.
58
Z
A
R
81
Fr
an
ce
6.
2
.1
4
29
�
1.
75
FR
A
82
In
di
a
6.
2
.5
5
18
.1
7
IN
D
1030
T
A
B
L
E
1
(C
on
tin
ue
d
)
Pa
rk
in
g
V
io
la
ti
on
s
R
an
k
C
ou
n
tr
y
N
am
e
V
io
la
ti
on
s
pe
r
D
ip
lo
m
at
,
Pr
e-
en
fo
rc
em
en
t
(1
1/
19
97
–1
1/
20
02
)
V
io
la
ti
on
s
pe
r
D
ip
lo
m
at
,
Po
st
en
fo
rc
em
en
t
(1
1/
20
02
–1
1/
20
05
)
U
N
M
is
si
on
D
ip
lo
m
at
s
in
19
98
C
or
ru
pt
io
n
In
de
x,
19
98
C
ou
n
tr
y
C
od
e
83
L
ao
s
6.
2
.0
0
9
.7
0
L
A
O
84
Tu
rk
m
en
is
ta
n
5.
9
.0
0
4
1.
13
T
K
M
85
Pa
pu
a
N
ew
G
ui
n
ea
5.
6
1.
74
3
.7
0
PN
G
86
H
on
du
ra
s
5.
5
.0
0
6
.7
5
H
N
D
87
Sl
ov
en
ia
5.
3
.4
5
8
�
.8
3
SV
N
88
K
yr
gy
zs
ta
n
5.
2
1.
05
5
.6
9
K
G
Z
89
N
ic
ar
ag
ua
4.
9
.4
4
9
.7
5
N
IC
90
U
ru
gu
ay
4.
5
.0
9
11
�
.4
2
U
R
Y
91
Sw
az
ila
n
d
4.
4
.4
7
7
.1
9
SW
Z
92
Ta
jik
is
ta
n
4.
4
.1
6
4
1.
12
T
JK
93
N
am
ib
ia
4.
3
.0
9
11
�
.2
4
N
A
M
94
M
ex
ic
o
4.
0
.0
2
19
.3
9
M
E
X
95
A
rg
en
ti
n
a
4.
0
.3
6
19
.2
2
A
R
G
96
Si
n
ga
po
re
3.
6
.1
6
6
�
2.
50
SG
P
97
R
om
an
ia
3.
6
.3
3
10
.3
8
R
O
M
98
U
ga
n
da
3.
5
.2
3
7
.6
2
U
G
A
99
H
un
ga
ry
3.
3
.0
8
8
�
.6
9
H
U
N
10
0
M
ac
ed
on
ia
3.
3
.1
6
4
.3
0
M
K
D
10
1
B
ol
iv
ia
3.
1
.0
0
9
.4
1
B
O
L
10
2
Pe
ru
3.
1
.3
6
9
.1
7
PE
R
10
3
H
ai
ti
3.
0
.0
4
9
.8
5
H
T
I
10
4
Jo
rd
an
3.
0
.0
0
9
�
.2
1
JO
R
10
5
B
el
ar
us
2.
7
.0
0
8
.6
0
B
L
R
10
6
B
el
gi
um
2.
7
.1
4
14
�
1.
23
B
E
L
10
7
C
yp
ru
s
2.
5
.0
6
11
�
1.
38
C
YP
10
8
G
uy
an
a
2.
3
.1
3
5
.2
6
G
U
Y
1031
10
9
A
us
tr
ia
2.
2
.5
1
21
�
2.
02
A
U
T
11
0
G
ab
on
2.
2
.2
9
8
.9
0
G
A
B
11
1
R
us
si
a
2.
1
.0
3
86
.6
9
R
U
S
11
2
L
it
h
ua
n
ia
2.
1
.0
5
7
�
.0
7
LT
U
11
3
E
l
Sa
lv
ad
or
1.
7
.2
6
10
.2
7
SL
V
11
4
Po
la
n
d
1.
7
.0
4
17
�
.4
9
PO
L
11
5
G
am
bi
a
1.
5
.2
9
8
.4
9
G
M
B
11
6
M
al
ay
si
a
1.
4
.2
0
13
�
.7
3
M
YS
11
7
Tr
in
id
ad
an
d
To
ba
go
1.
4
.1
6
6
�
.1
3
T
T
O
11
8
L
eb
an
on
1.
4
.0
0
3
.3
2
L
B
N
11
9
G
er
m
an
y
1.
0
.1
0
52
�
2.
21
D
E
U
12
0
E
ri
tr
ea
.8
.0
0
3
�
.4
6
E
R
I
12
1
M
ol
do
va
.7
.0
0
4
.5
1
M
D
A
12
2
K
or
ea
(S
ou
th
)
.4
.1
9
33
�
.1
1
K
O
R
12
3
D
om
in
ic
an
R
ep
ub
lic
.1
.0
0
22
.5
3
D
O
M
12
4
Fi
n
la
n
d
.1
.0
0
18
�
2.
55
FI
N
12
5
G
ua
te
m
al
a
.1
.0
7
9
.6
3
G
T
M
12
6
Sw
it
ze
rl
an
d
.1
.0
0
10
�
2.
58
C
H
E
12
7
N
ew
Z
ea
la
n
d
.1
.0
0
8
�
2.
55
N
Z
L
12
8
U
n
it
ed
K
in
gd
om
.0
.0
1
31
�
2.
33
G
B
R
12
9
N
et
h
er
la
n
ds
.0
.1
0
17
�
2.
48
N
L
D
13
0
U
n
it
ed
A
ra
b
E
m
ir
at
es
.0
.0
0
3
�
.7
8
A
R
E
13
1
A
us
tr
al
ia
.0
.0
3
12
�
2.
21
A
U
S
13
2
A
ze
rb
ai
ja
n
.0
.9
8
5
1.
01
A
Z
E
13
3
B
ur
ki
n
a-
Fa
so
.0
.2
0
5
.5
1
B
FA
13
4
C
en
tr
al
A
fr
ic
an
R
ep
ub
lic
.0
.0
0
3
.5
5
C
A
F
13
5
C
an
ad
a
.0
.0
0
24
�
2.
51
C
A
N
13
6
C
ol
om
bi
a
.0
.0
0
16
.6
1
C
O
L
13
7
D
en
m
ar
k
.0
.0
2
17
�
2.
57
D
N
K
13
8
E
cu
ad
or
.0
.0
0
9
.7
4
E
C
U
13
9
G
re
ec
e
.0
.1
1
21
�
.8
5
G
R
C
14
0
Ir
el
an
d
.0
.0
7
10
�
2.
15
IR
L
14
1
Is
ra
el
.0
.0
9
15
�
1.
41
IS
R
14
2
Ja
m
ai
ca
.0
.0
0
9
.2
6
JA
M
T
A
B
L
E
1
(C
on
tin
ue
d
)
Pa
rk
in
g
V
io
la
ti
on
s
R
an
k
C
ou
n
tr
y
N
am
e
V
io
la
ti
on
s
pe
r
D
ip
lo
m
at
,
Pr
e-
en
fo
rc
em
en
t
(1
1/
19
97
–1
1/
20
02
)
V
io
la
ti
on
s
pe
r
D
ip
lo
m
at
,
Po
st
en
fo
rc
em
en
t
(1
1/
20
02
–1
1/
20
05
)
U
N
M
is
si
on
D
ip
lo
m
at
s
in
19
98
C
or
ru
pt
io
n
In
de
x,
19
98
C
ou
n
tr
y
C
od
e
14
3
Ja
pa
n
.0
.0
1
47
�
1.
16
JP
N
14
4
L
at
vi
a
.0
.0
0
5
.1
0
LV
A
14
5
N
or
w
ay
.0
.0
0
12
�
2.
35
N
O
R
14
6
O
m
an
.0
.2
6
5
�
.8
9
O
M
N
14
7
Pa
n
am
a
.0
.0
0
8
.2
8
PA
N
14
8
Sw
ed
en
.0
.0
0
19
�
2.
55
SW
E
14
9
Tu
rk
ey
.0
.0
0
25
.0
1
T
U
R
N
o
te
.—
T
h
e
co
rr
up
ti
on
in
de
x
is
fr
om
K
au
fm
an
n
et
al
.
(2
00
5)
.A
h
ig
h
er
sc
or
e
in
th
e
co
rr
up
ti
on
in
de
x
de
n
ot
es
m
or
e
co
rr
up
ti
on
.
corruption, norms, and legal enforcement 1033
Fig. 1.—Total monthly New York City parking violations by diplomats, 1997–2005 (ver-
tical axis on log scale).
III. Cross-Country Data
We employ country-level data on economic, political, and social char-
acteristics and in particular consider data on country corruption levels
using the measure in Kaufmann, Kraay, and Mastruzzi (2005) from 1998,
the earliest year with wide country coverage. This is a composite cor-
ruption index that is essentially the first principal component of a num-
ber of other commonly used corruption indices, which are usually sub-
jective measures based on surveys of country experts and investors. By
definition, therefore, the Kaufmann et al. measure is highly correlated
with the commonly used indices and is extremely highly correlated
( ) with the Transparency International ratings from the samer p 0.97
year. For ease of interpretation, we reverse the sign of the original mea-
sure so that higher values indicate greater corruption. By construction,
the mean value of this measure across all countries in their sample is
zero with standard deviation one, and it ranges from �2.6 to �1.6 in
our slightly restricted sample of countries. The main advantages of this
country measure are that its method of aggregation is clearly defined
relative to the Transparency International measure, and it has broader
country coverage than other indices. Our sample consists of all countries
that had 1998 populations greater than 500,000 according to the World
Development Indicators, and for which basic country-level data were
1034 journal of political economy
TABLE 2
Descriptive Statistics
Variable Mean
Standard
Deviation Observations
A. Country-Level Data
Unpaid New York City parking violations:a
11/1997–11/2002 977.9 2,000.9 149
11/2002–11/2005 11.3 18.4 149
Unpaid and paid New York City parking
violations, 11/1997–11/2002a 1,066.2 2,021.4 149
After-hours New York city parking viola-
tions, 11/1997–11/2002 a 40.6 72.7 149
Diplomats in the country UN mission,
1998b 11.8 11.1 149
Number of license plates registered to the
country’s UN mission, 2006c 10.5 14.0 139
Country corruption index, 1998d .01 1.01 149
Log per capita income (1998 US$)e 7.35 1.59 149
Average government wage/country per
capita income, early 1990sf 2.83 2.38 92
Log weighted distance between
populationsg 9.12 .41 149
Log total trade with the United States
(1998 US$)h 20.3 2.7 146
Received U.S. economic aid (indicator),
1998i .69 .46 147
Received U.S. military aid (indicator),
1998i .63 .49 147
B. Diplomat-Level Data
Monthly unpaid New York City parking
violations:a
11/1997–11/2002 .90 3.30 25,123
11/2002–11/2005 .02 .19 15,806
Length of time at the UN mission in New
York City (in months)b 7.7 12.4 40,929
a Source: New York City, Parking Violations Database (provided to the authors by the New York City Department of
Finance).
b Source: United Nations Blue Books, 1997–2005.
c Source: U.S. Department of State Office of Foreign Missions (provided to the authors by Deputy Director Murray
Smith).
d Composite index from Kaufmann et al. (2005), but here higher values indicate more corruption.
e Source: World Development Indicators (2005).
f Source: Schiavo-Campo et al. (1999); exact year differs by country.
g Source: Mayer and Zignago (2005).
h Source: U.S. International Trade Commission (2006).
i Data from Kuziemko and Werker (2006).
available. Table 2 presents summary statistics for both the country-level
and diplomat-level variables.
We include a number of other variables that may affect incentives to
comply with local laws. From the data set used by Kuziemko and Werker
(2006), we generate an indicator variable denoting whether the country
received foreign aid from the United States in 1998. We similarly gen-
erate a pair of indicator variables for military and economic aid, since
corruption, norms, and legal enforcement 1035
these two types of aid may reflect different geopolitical interests: while
economic aid recipients may feel beholden to the United States, those
receiving military aid are typically countries that the United States seeks
as strategic allies.
Finally, we include the logarithm of 1998 GDP per capita in U.S.
dollars (taken from the World Development Indicators) in most spec-
ifications to control for income effects. Country-level income per capita
is strongly correlated with corruption and with the rule of law, and some
argue that income is influenced by underlying corruption levels, com-
plicating efforts to disentangle corruption effects from income effects.
As we discuss below, despite this strong correlation, the main corruption
results are robust to including income controls. Second, we include the
ratio of government bureaucrats’ salaries to GDP per capita (using data
from Schiavo-Campo, de Tommaso, and Mukherjee [1999]) for the early
1990s (exact year differs by country) to account for the possibility that
bureaucrats occupy different positions in the national income
distribution.
IV. Empirical Results
A count model analysis is appropriate given the dependent variable, the
total number of unpaid parking violations by country. We focus on the
negative binomial model (the Poisson model can be rejected at high
levels of confidence because of overdispersion of the parking tickets
outcome variable; result not shown). In the main econometric specifi-
cation for the cross-country analysis, the dependent variable is Total
Unpaid Parking Violationsit, where i denotes the country. There are two
time periods t per country, one for the pre-enforcement period and one
for the postenforcement period. Standard errors are robustly estimated,
and the disturbance terms for a country are allowed to be correlated.
The vector of explanatory variables is
′b Corruption � b Enforcement � b Diplomats � X g,1 i 2 it 3 i i
where Corruption is the 1998 country corruption index; Enforcement
is an indicator for the post–October 2002 period, when legal enforce-
ment increased sharply against diplomatic parking violators; and X is a
vector of other country controls, including the log of 1998 GDP per
capita, and region fixed effects,12 among others depending on the
specification.
The New York City unpaid parking violations measure is robustly
12 United Nations region code data, available at http://unstats.un.org/unsd/methods/
m49/m49regin.htm, were used to classify countries into the following regions: (1) North
America (including Caribbean), (2) South America, (3) Europe, (4) Asia, (5) Oceania,
(6) Africa, and (7) Middle East.
1036 journal of political economy
positively correlated with the existing subjective country corruption in-
dex conditional on the number of UN mission diplomats for that coun-
try in New York City (table 3, regression 1). The relationship is roughly
linear (fig. 2). The coefficient implies that the increase in the corruption
index associated with going from a highly corrupt country such as Ni-
geria (corruption score �1.01) to a largely uncorrupt country such as
Norway (score �2.35) is associated with a large drop of 48 log points
# 3.36 p 161 log points, or approximately 80 percent, in the average
rate of diplomatic parking violations. The result is nearly unchanged if
Kuwait, the country with the most parking violations per diplomat, is
dropped from the sample (not shown). Parking violations also plummet
in the postenforcement period, by over 98 percent on average, indi-
cating that legal enforcement is also highly influential.
The coefficient estimate on the country corruption index is robust
to the inclusion of log per capita income (table 3, regression 2). This
pattern argues strongly against the explanation that richer countries are
simply able to purchase more parking spots for their diplomats, in which
case we would expect a weakening of the relationship between country
corruption and parking violations and a negative coefficient estimate
on country income, but we find neither. The result is also robust to
controlling for region fixed effects (regression 3). The Middle East and
Africa are the regions with the greatest average number of unpaid park-
ing violations relative to the reference region (North America and the
Caribbean). The inclusion of higher-order polynomial controls for in-
come (regression 4) and an interaction between country corruption
and the postenforcement period (regression 5) also has little effect on
the partial correlation of the corruption index with parking violations
committed. The interaction term between country corruption and the
postenforcement period indicator variable has little predictive power,
indicating a largely stable relationship across the pre- and postenforce-
ment periods (see fig. 3).
The results are robust to including the average government wage
relative to per capita income (table 4, regression 1) and also to the
number of vehicles registered to each mission (regression 2).13 The
inclusion of paid violations in our parking violations measure has no
effect on the main results (regression 3), further arguing against the
possibility that our country corruption measure is picking up an income
effect rather than a corruption effect.
There is also strong evidence that many violations are not work re-
lated. We focus on the subset of violations committed between the night-
time hours of 10:00 p.m. and 6:00 a.m. at a distance of more than five
13 A specification using fixed effects for the number of vehicles per mission generates
similar results (not shown).
TABLE 3
Country Characteristics and Unpaid New York City Parking Violations,
November 1997 to November 2005
Dependent Variable: Unpaid Parking Violations
(1) (2) (3) (4) (5)
Country corruption index,
1998 .48*** .57*** .57*** .56** .57*
(.18) (.22) (.21) (.28) (.30)
Postenforcement period
indicator (post-11/2002) �4.41*** �4.41*** �4.21*** �4.43*** �4.41***
(.21) (.21) (.13) (.20) (.21)
Country corruption index
# postenforcement
period �.01
(.28)
Diplomats .05** .04** .05*** .05** .04**
(.02) (.02) (.02) (.02) (.02)
Log per capita income
(1998 US$) .06 .09 64.2* .06
(.14) (.14) (36.9) (.14)
Africa region indicator
variable 2.86***
(.48)
Asia region indicator
variable 1.99***
(.50)
Europe region indicator
variable 2.24***
(.55)
Latin America region indi-
cator variable 1.67***
(.56)
Middle East region indica-
tor variable 3.23***
(.60)
Oceania region indicator
variable 1.51**
(.64)
Log per capita income
(1998 US$) polynomials
(quadratic, cubic,
quartic) No No No Yes No
Observations 298 298 298 298 298
Log pseudolikelihood �1,570.21 �1,570.07 �1,547.69 �1,567.56 �1,570.07
Note.—Negative binomial regressions. White robust standard errors are in parentheses. Disturbance terms are clus-
tered by country (there are two observations per country: pre-enforcement and postenforcement). The omitted region
category is North America/Caribbean.
* Statistically significantly different from zero at 90 percent confidence.
** Statistically significantly different from zero at 95 percent confidence.
*** Statistically significantly different from zero at 99 percent confidence.
1038 journal of political economy
Fig. 2.—Country corruption and unpaid New York City parking violations per diplomat
(in logs), pre-enforcement (November 1997 to November 2002). Country abbreviations
are presented in table 1. The line is the quadratic regression fit. The y-axis is log(1 �
Annual NYC Parking Violations/Diplomat).
city blocks (roughly one-quarter mile) away from the UN complex,
where most of the missions are centered. We find that a similar rela-
tionship between the country corruption and legal enforcement terms
also holds for this subset of violations (table 4, regression 4).14
The strong relationship between the parking violation corruption
measure and the country corruption index is robust to different func-
tional forms. It also holds if the dependent variable is log(1 � Unpaid
Parking Violations) across specifications (table 4, regression 5) and is
14 The results in tables 3 and 4 are nearly identical if distance from the country’s UN
mission to the UN Plaza is included as an additional explanatory variable (results not
shown). We also examined the most socially egregious New York City parking violations.
While impoverished diplomats from poor countries might be forced to park illegally in
order to avoid the extra expense of renting a parking spot, they could still try to do so
in a manner that avoids excessive negative social externalities. As indications of “extreme”
violations, we considered (i) parking in front of a fire hydrant and (ii) violations for
double-parking on east-west streets between Tenth and 100th streets in Manhattan, rela-
tively narrow streets where double-parking can completely block passage. The main results
hold robustly for both types of violations (not shown); in other words, diplomats from
high-corruption countries are much more likely to commit the most egregious violations.
Hence our results are not driven solely by behaviors causing minimal social harm (i.e.,
an expired meter in a legal parking spot) or those in which it may be unclear to the
diplomat that he or she is generating negative externalities.
corruption, norms, and legal enforcement 1039
Fig. 3.—Country corruption and unpaid New York City parking violations per diplomat
(in logs), postenforcement (November 2002 to November 2005). Country abbreviations
are presented in table 1. The line is the quadratic regression fit. The y-axis is log(1 �
Annual NYC Parking Violations/Diplomat).
similar for an ordinary least squares (OLS) specification with unpaid
violations as the dependent variable (regression 6).
Several measures of “proximity” to the United States are correlated
with fewer unpaid parking violations. First, the log of the weighted
average distance between a country’s population and the U.S. popula-
tion15 is strongly positively correlated with parking violations (table 4,
regression 7), indicating that diplomats from countries in closer geo-
graphic proximity to the United States have many fewer New York City
violations. We do not have a definitive explanation for this pattern;
however, we note that it is not driven by trade volumes, which are not
a statistically significant predictor of parking violations (coefficient es-
timate 0.04, standard error 0.07). Migration, tourism, and some broader
cultural affinity between the countries are other possible explanations.
Countries that receive U.S. economic aid are significantly less likely to
commit diplomatic parking violations (with a large effect of 65 log
15 Distance from the United States is taken from Mayer and Zignago (2005). Their
measure uses city-level data to assess the geographic distribution of population inside each
nation and calculates the distance between two countries on the basis of bilateral distances
between the largest cities of those two countries, those intercity distances being weighted
by the share of the city in the overall country’s population.
1040
T
A
B
L
E
4
C
o
u
n
tr
y
C
h
ar
ac
te
ri
st
ic
s
an
d
U
n
pa
id
N
ew
Yo
rk
C
it
y
Pa
rk
in
g
V
io
la
ti
o
n
s,
N
o
ve
m
be
r
19
97
to
N
o
ve
m
be
r
20
05
:
Se
n
si
ti
vi
ty
Te
st
s
D
ep
en
d
en
t
Va
ri
ab
le
U
n
pa
id
Pa
rk
in
g
V
io
la
ti
on
s
N
eg
at
iv
e
B
in
om
ia
l
(1
)
U
n
pa
id
Pa
rk
in
g
V
io
la
ti
on
s
N
eg
at
iv
e
B
in
om
ia
l
(2
)
Pa
id
an
d
U
n
pa
id
Pa
rk
in
g
V
io
la
ti
on
s
N
eg
at
iv
e
B
in
om
ia
l
(3
)
A
ft
er
-H
ou
rs
Pa
rk
in
g
V
io
la
ti
on
s
N
eg
at
iv
e
B
in
om
ia
l
(4
)
L
og
(1
�
U
n
pa
id
Pa
rk
in
g
V
io
la
ti
on
s)
O
L
S
(5
)
U
n
pa
id
Pa
rk
in
g
V
io
la
ti
on
s
O
L
S
(6
)
U
n
pa
id
Pa
rk
in
g
V
io
la
ti
on
s
N
eg
at
iv
e
B
in
om
ia
l
(7
)
C
ou
n
tr
y
co
rr
up
ti
on
in
de
x,
19
98
1.
01
**
*
.4
8*
*
.4
7*
*
.5
6*
.3
7*
*
12
3.
9*
.7
4*
**
(.
32
)
(.
24
)
(.
18
)
(.
30
)
(.
16
)
(7
2.
3)
(.
23
)
Po
st
en
fo
rc
em
en
t
pe
ri
od
in
di
ca
to
r
(p
os
t-1
1/
20
02
)
�
4.
06
**
*
�
4.
31
**
*
�
3.
36
**
*
�
3.
52
**
*
�
2.
69
**
*
�
96
6.
6*
**
�
4.
34
**
*
(.
15
)
(.
19
)
(.
16
)
(.
21
)
(.
14
)
(1
64
.6
)
(.
19
)
D
ip
lo
m
at
s
.0
6*
*
.0
1
.0
5*
**
.0
4*
21
.1
*
.0
5
(.
03
)
(.
02
)
(.
02
)
(.
02
)
(1
1.
2)
(.
03
)
L
og
pe
r
ca
pi
ta
in
co
m
e
(1
99
8
U
S$
)
.3
2
.0
1
.0
6
�
.0
2
�
.2
4*
*
�
40
.0
.0
2
(.
20
)
(.
14
)
(.
13
)
(.
17
)
(.
10
)
(6
8.
4)
(.
17
)
A
ve
ra
ge
go
ve
rn
m
en
t
w
ag
e/
co
un
tr
y
pe
r
ca
pi
ta
in
co
m
e
.1
5*
*
(.
06
)
1041
D
ip
lo
m
at
ic
ve
h
ic
le
s
.0
5*
(.
02
)
L
og
di
pl
om
at
s
.7
5*
**
(.
15
)
L
og
w
ei
gh
te
d
di
st
an
ce
of
po
pu
la
ti
on
fr
om
U
n
it
ed
St
at
es
1.
23
**
*
(.
30
)
L
og
to
ta
l
tr
ad
e
w
it
h
th
e
U
n
it
ed
St
at
es
.0
4
(.
07
)
R
ec
ei
ve
d
U
.S
.
ec
on
om
ic
ai
d
�
.6
5*
*
(.
30
)
R
ec
ei
ve
d
U
.S
.
m
ili
ta
ry
ai
d
.1
0
(.
23
)
O
bs
er
va
ti
on
s
18
4
27
8
29
8
29
8
29
8
29
8
28
8
L
og
ps
eu
do
lik
el
ih
oo
d
�
96
7.
23
�
1,
46
3.
60
�
1,
81
6.
45
�
83
1.
14
.
.
.
.
.
.
�
1,
51
0.
79
2
R
.
.
.
.
.
.
.
.
.
.
.
.
.5
2
.1
3
.
.
.
N
o
te
.—
W
h
it
e
ro
bu
st
st
an
da
rd
er
ro
rs
ar
e
in
pa
re
n
th
es
es
.
D
is
tu
rb
an
ce
s
ar
e
cl
us
te
re
d
by
co
un
tr
y.
*
St
at
is
ti
ca
lly
si
gn
ifi
ca
n
tl
y
di
ff
er
en
t
fr
om
ze
ro
at
90
pe
rc
en
t
co
n
fi
de
n
ce
.
**
St
at
is
ti
ca
lly
si
gn
ifi
ca
n
tl
y
di
ff
er
en
t
fr
om
ze
ro
at
95
pe
rc
en
t
co
n
fi
de
n
ce
.
**
*
St
at
is
ti
ca
lly
si
gn
ifi
ca
n
tl
y
di
ff
er
en
t
fr
om
ze
ro
at
99
pe
rc
en
t
co
n
fi
de
n
ce
.
1042 journal of political economy
points), suggesting that the goodwill engendered by these ties may help
to limit abuse of diplomatic privileges in New York and pointing to the
broader role of sentiment in driving norm compliance.16
Since we can follow individual diplomats during their tenure at the
United Nations, we examine the related question of how diplomat be-
havior evolves while in New York City. Conceptually, the relative plau-
sibility of socialization to U.S. norms versus convergence to a uniform
high-corruption norm is unclear. If convergence is to U.S. corruption
norms, individuals from high-corruption countries (e.g., Nigeria) should
have declining parking violations over time, but there should be no
change in behavior for diplomats from the low-corruption societies (e.g.,
Norway). Alternatively, individuals may begin their stay in New York City
unsure as to the extent to which they can get away with violations. Once
they successfully “got away with it” a few times (or heard stories about
others doing so), diplomats may become bolder in their violations. Thus
convergence to this zero-enforcement norm predicts increasing viola-
tions over time, particularly among diplomats from less corrupt
countries.
In practice, to estimate these effects, we use a negative binomial re-
gression like that discussed above, but with observations at the diplomat-
month level of analysis. We include month-year fixed effects ( ). Theat
two key explanatory variables are the effect of increased time spent
working as a consular official in New York City on parking violations
and the differential time effect for diplomats from countries with higher
corruption (the interaction effect of time spent working in New York
City with the country corruption index). Disturbance terms are allowed
to be correlated across the monthly observations for the same individual.
The parking violations included in the individual-level analysis are a
subset of those used at the country level: violations committed using
official consular vehicles are excluded below since they cannot be
matched to any one diplomat.
The frequency of unpaid violations increases rapidly and statistically
significantly with tenure in New York City (table 5, regression 1), seem-
ingly ruling out convergence to the U.S. norm of rule adherence. On
average, parking violations increase by 8.4 percent with each additional
16 An additional direct measure of affinity is provided by the Pew Global Attitudes Survey
from 2002 (the earliest year that the survey was performed), based on responses to the
question “Please tell me if you have a very favorable, somewhat favorable, somewhat un-
favorable, or very unfavorable opinion of the United States.” This is coded to take on
values from one (most favorable) to four (least favorable) and then averaged across re-
spondents. In some specifications, the anti-U.S. sentiment term is a large and statistically
significant predictor of more parking violations (see Fisman and Miguel 2006). However,
the result does not robustly hold when the negative binomial specification is used, and
thus we do not emphasize it. A main limitation of the analysis with the Pew data is the
small sample of only 42 countries. The data are available at http://pewglobal.org/.
corruption, norms, and legal enforcement 1043
TABLE 5
Unpaid Parking Violations at the Diplomat level, November 1997 to
November 2005
Dependent Variable:
Unpaid Parking Viola-
tions (Monthly)
Negative
Binomial
(1)
Negative
Binomial
(2)
Country corruption index, 1998 .150 .390***
(.120) (.117)
Log length of time in New York City (in
months) .084*** .090***
(.005) (.006)
Log length of time in New York City # coun-
try corruption index �.027***
(.006)
Month fixed effects Yes Yes
Observations (diplomats) 40,929
(5,338)
40,929
(5,338)
Log pseudolikelihood �23,733 �23,621
Note.—White robust standard errors are in parentheses. Disturbance terms are clustered by country. Observations
are at the diplomat-month level. Month fixed effects are included in all regressions (thus the postenforcement
indicator is not included). The log per capita income (1998 US$) term is included as a control in cols. 1–2 (results
not shown).
* Statistically significantly different from zero at 90 percent confidence.
** Statistically significantly different from zero at 95 percent confidence.
*** Statistically significantly different from zero at 99 percent confidence.
month a diplomat lives in New York, perhaps as he or she learns about
the reality of diplomatic immunity. Diplomats from low-corruption coun-
tries show the most rapid proportional increases in violations over time
(regression 2), consistent with partial convergence to the zero-enforce-
ment norm, although the large proportional increases among diplomats
from low-corruption countries are from a much lower base rate of vi-
olations. This increase in parking violations among those from low-
corruption countries occurs almost entirely in the pre-enforcement pe-
riod (result not shown), an indication that their attachment to home
country anticorruption norms was partly eroded by time spent in New
York City’s lawless pre–November 2002 parking environment.17
Alternative explanations.—Informal or formal social sanctions against
diplomats in the home country could be partially responsible for re-
straining parking violations through, for example, public embarrass-
ment in the media upon returning home or punishment by the dip-
17 Similar results hold with alternative specifications, including a linear regression model
(not shown). When diplomat fixed effects are included in a linear model, the coefficient
estimate on the interaction between months in New York City and country corruption is
negative but no longer statistically significant. Results are virtually identical if individuals
who arrived only after the earliest UN Blue Book was published are excluded, which allows
us to more accurately capture tenure in New York City (not shown).
1044 journal of political economy
lomatic service. If the potential response of others in the home country,
either informally or formally, is responsible for limiting parking viola-
tions, then diplomats’ behaviors are better interpreted as an indication
of their home country’s cultural tolerance for corruption rather than
their own personal values. However, this is still consistent with the basic
interpretation of the level of New York City parking violations as a re-
vealed preference measure of country corruption norms in the absence
of formal legal enforcement. In such cases, diplomats’ behaviors are
better interpreted as an indication of their home country’s norms or
culture rather than their own personal values.
Several findings argue somewhat against this interpretation that non-
legal punishments such as media embarrassment or workplace punish-
ment are the main drivers of our findings. First, a Lexis-Nexis search
of 504 European news outlets (English language or in translation) using
the terms “diplomats” and “parking” and “New York” yielded only 25
stories during the entire study period, and these stories were concen-
trated in just four countries (the United Kingdom, Germany, France,
and Russia). Further, with the exception of several Russian articles, the
stories were about the general problem of diplomatic parking violations
in New York City and the 2002 crackdown rather than reporting on the
behavior of home country diplomats. The possibility of sanctions for
returning diplomats who accumulated parking tickets while abroad is
apparently not a leading media issue, in Europe at least.
Second, we considered whether unpaid parking violations early in an
official’s tenure at the United Nations in New York City are correlated
with the length of his employment there, and further whether these
early violations interact in any way with corruption in the country of
origin (i.e., perhaps violators from low-corruption countries could be
punished by their government and sent home early). We find no evi-
dence for any such effects of parking violations on diplomat tenure
(regressions not shown).
Obviously, neither of these two findings is completely conclusive in
terms of pinning down the exact channel for the culture results. In
equilibrium the number of violations committed could reflect choices
made, in part, to avoid home country sanctions. But they are certainly
consistent with the widely held view among New York City officials that
home country enforcement is typically weak or nonexistent.18 A related
concern is that public pressure could have a larger effect on diplomats’
choices in a more democratic political setting. However, we do not find
that the number of parking violations is statistically significantly related
18 Gillian Sorensen, former New York City Commissioner for the United Nations and
Consular Affairs in the 1980s, claims that during her tenure UN missions in New York
City rarely, if ever, punished their employees for parking tickets, even in the most egregious
cases (personal communication, February 8, 2007).
corruption, norms, and legal enforcement 1045
to democracy (as measured by the Polity IV democracy scale in 1998),
nor is the coefficient on corruption affected at all by its inclusion (re-
gressions not shown).19
V. Conclusion
We exploit a unique natural experiment—the stationing in New York
City of thousands of government officials from 149 countries around
the world—in a setting of zero legal enforcement of parking violations
to construct a revealed preference measure of official corruption, and
then estimate how behavior changes when legal enforcement increased.
We find that the number of diplomatic parking violations is strongly
correlated with existing measures of home country corruption. This
finding suggests that cultural or social norms related to corruption are
quite persistent: even when stationed thousands of miles away, diplomats
behave in a manner highly reminiscent of government officials in the
home country. Norms related to corruption are apparently deeply in-
grained, and factors other than legal enforcement are important de-
terminants of corruption behavior. Nonetheless, increased legal en-
forcement is also highly influential: parking violations fell by over 98
percent after enforcement was introduced. New York City is an attractive
location to study increased enforcement relative to many less developed
countries, where official changes “on the books” may not always translate
into greater actual enforcement on the ground.
The result on sticky corruption cultures raises the critical question of
whether there are policy interventions that can modify corruption norms
over time. For example, the Bloomberg administration’s enforcement
efforts in New York City in 2002 were extremely successful in changing
diplomats’ behaviors, and it would be useful to know whether these
changes might additionally have had persistent effects on norms once
individuals become habituated to rule-compliant behavior. Such long-
run effects of temporary interventions necessarily rely on a shift in norms
(or tastes) and would be consistent with the findings of Di Tella and
Schargrodsky (2003) on the persistent effects of auditing on corruption
19 A final consideration is whether there is a differential selection mechanism for UN
diplomats across countries that might account for the pattern we observe. In particular,
it would be problematic if the relatively more corrupt government officials (within the
distribution of officials in a country) were selected for New York postings from high-
corruption countries. We have no rigorous statistical test to explore this possibility, but
we feel that it is unlikely to be of first-order importance for several reasons. First, UN
mission staff are selected along a range of common characteristics, including English
language skills, education, and diplomatic experience, and this reduces the gap between
diplomats in terms of their personal attributes. Further, we are not concerned with dif-
ferential selection of “corrupt” types into the government bureaucracy vs. the private sector
across countries, since we are interested in the behavior of actual government civil servants,
such as the UN mission diplomats we observe.
1046 journal of political economy
in Argentina. Unfortunately, our context does not accommodate this
analysis. Understanding better how corruption norms evolve is likely to
be critical for the success of anticorruption reforms such as those cur-
rently widely advocated by the World Bank and other foreign aid donors.
Data Appendix
A. New York City Diplomatic Parking Violation Data
The New York City Department of Finance supplied listings of all unpaid parking
violations of UN missions. The violations covered the period from November
24, 1997, to November 21, 2005. In order to appear in the database, a violation
had to go unpaid for at least 100 days. Data were at the level of the violation
and included the following entries for each violation:
• Summons: unique identification number for the violation
• License plate number of the violating car
• The person to whom the violating car was registered, often the mission
itself
• Time of violation: included both hour and minute as well as calendar date
• Type of violation, e.g., expired meter, fire hydrant
• Street address of violation
• Initial dollar value of fine issued
• Additional dollar penalty for not having paid the fine on time
• Amount paid toward the fine, generally zero
• Name of country to which the car is registered
Data on UN diplomats’ paid parking violations (violations that did not go
into arrears) were made available to us in aggregate form by the New York City
Department of Finance.
B. UN Blue Books
The United Nations issues its list of mission personnel, or Blue Book, twice
yearly. We utilize edition numbers 278 (January 1997) through 294 (October
2005). Documents were retrieved from the UN Official Document System, avail-
able at http://documents.un.org/advance.asp. Searching for the symbol ST/
SG/SER.A/### with truncation turned off returns the relevant Blue Book (where
### is the Blue Book edition number). Edition 280 (May 1998) was checked by
hand to count the mission staff and spouses for each country in the Blue Book,
producing the following variables:
• Mission: indicator variable indicating whether the country had a UN
mission
• Staff: simple count of staff (staff members are always listed with their sur-
names in bold)
To create the longitudinal data set of diplomat parking violations, the Blue
Book data were first converted into filtered html format. A program was used
to parse the name and country of each diplomat in each Blue Book. Next,
diplomat names from the Blue Books were matched to the parking violation
data. A name was considered to have “matched” if the country, last name, and
first four letters of the first name corresponded across data sets. There was some
corruption, norms, and legal enforcement 1047
manual double-checking of apparent spelling typos and duplicate or otherwise
confusing names. Diplomats are considered “present” in New York City in the
analysis for the months after their first appearance in a Blue Book and before
the first Blue Book in which they no longer appear. Since Blue Books are pro-
duced only sporadically, in months between a final Blue Book appearance and
the first “nonappearance,” we assume arbitrarily that diplomats left New York
at the midpoint in time between these months.
C. Diplomatic Vehicles
Data were provided by Murray Smith, Deputy Director at the U.S. State De-
partment’s Office of Foreign Missions in April 2006. These data report counts
of the number of vehicles with diplomatic license plates registered to each
mission in early 2006.
References
Agence France–Presse. 2005. “Speedy Diplomats Steer Clear of Fines in France.”
March 16.
BBC News. 1998. “So What Are Diplomats Immune To?” October 28. http://
news.bbc.co.uk/1/hi/special_report/1998/10/98/e-cyclopedia/196677.stm.
Becker, Gary S. 1968. “Crime and Punishment: An Economic Approach.” J.P.E.
76 (March/April): 169–217.
Borjas, George J. 2000. “The Economic Progress of Immigrants.” In Issues in the
Economics of Immigration, edited by George J. Borjas. Chicago: Univ. Chicago
Press (for NBER).
Di Tella, Rafael, and Ernesto Schargrodsky. 2003. “The Role of Wages and Au-
diting during a Crackdown on Corruption in the City of Buenos Aires.” J.
Law and Econ. 46 (April): 269–92.
Fernandez, Raquel, and Alessandra Fogli. 2006. “Fertility: The Role of Culture
and Family Experience.” J. European Econ. Assoc. 4 (April–May): 552–61.
Fisman, Raymond, and Edward Miguel. 2006. “Cultures of Corruption: Evidence
from Diplomatic Parking Tickets.” Working Paper no. 12312 (June), NBER,
Cambridge, MA.
Fries, Jacob H. 2002. “U.S. Revokes License Plates Issued to 185 at 30 Consulates.”
New York Times, September 7.
Ichino, Andrea, and Giovanni Maggi. 2000. “Work Environment and Individual
Background: Explaining Regional Shirking Differentials in a Large Italian
Firm.” Q.J.E. 115 (August): 1057–90.
Kaufmann, Daniel, Aart Kraay, and Massimo Mastruzzi. 2005. “Governance Mat-
ters IV: Governance Indicators for 1996–2004.” Policy Research Working Paper
no. 3630, World Bank, Washington, DC.
Korea Times. 1999. “Illegal Parking by Diplomats on Rise.” November 1.
Kuziemko, Ilyana, and Eric Werker. 2006. “How Much Is a Seat on the Security
Council Worth? Foreign Aid and Bribery at the United Nations.” J.P.E. 114
(October): 905–30.
Lambsdorff, Johann Graf. 2006. “Causes and Consequences of Corruption: What
Do We Know from a Cross-Section of Countries?” In International Handbook
on the Economics of Corruption, edited by Susan Rose-Ackerman. Northampton,
MA: Elgar.
Ledyard, John O. 1995. “Public Goods: A Survey of Experimental Research.” In
1048 journal of political economy
The Handbook of Experimental Economics, edited by John H. Kagel and Alvin E.
Roth. Princeton, NJ: Princeton Univ. Press.
Levitt, Steven D. 1997. “Using Electoral Cycles in Police Hiring to Estimate the
Effect of Police on Crime.” A.E.R. 87 (June): 270–90.
———. 2004. “Understanding Why Crime Fell in the 1990s: Four Factors That
Explain the Decline and Six That Do Not.” J. Econ. Perspectives 18 (Winter):
163–90.
———. 2006. “An Economist Sells Bagels: A Case Study in Profit Maximization.”
Working Paper no. 12152 (April), NBER, Cambridge, MA.
Mauro, Paolo. 2004. “The Persistence of Corruption and Slow Economic
Growth.” IMF Staff Papers 51 (1): 1–18.
Mayer, Thierry, and Soledad Zignago. 2005. “Market Access in Global and Re-
gional Trade.” Working Paper no. 2005-02 (January), Centre d’Etudes Pros-
pectives et d’Informations Internationales, Paris.
Olken, Benjamin A. 2006. “Corruption Perceptions vs. Corruption Reality.” Man-
uscript, Harvard Univ.
Reinikka, Ritva, and Jakob Svensson. 2004. “Local Capture: Evidence from a
Central Government Transfer Program in Uganda.” Q.J.E. 119 (May): 679–
705.
Rockwell, John. 2004. “Reverberations: Where Mimes Patrolled the Streets and
the Mayor Was Superman.” New York Times, July 9.
Schiavo-Campo, Salvatore, Giulio de Tommaso, and Amit Mukherjee. 1999. “An
International Statistical Survey of Government Employment and Wages.” Pol-
icy Research Working Paper no. 1806, World Bank, Washington, DC.
Singleton, Don. 2004. “Bill Socks Scofflaw Diplos.” New York Daily News, November
21, p. 28.
Steinhauer, Jennifer. 2002. “Suspension of Hostilities over Diplomats’ Tickets.”
New York Times, August 23.
Tirole, Jean. 1996. “A Theory of Collective Reputations (with Applications to
the Persistence of Corruption and to Firm Quality).” Rev. Econ. Studies 63
(January): 1–22.
Witzel, Morgen. 2005. “How to Respond When Only Bribe Money Talks.” Fi-
nancial Times, July 11, London ed. 1, p. 14.
CountryData.Rdata
CountryData.Rdata
__MACOSX/._CountryData.Rdata
Homework Assignment 3:
Models, Interactions, Threats to Validity
Quantitative Methods II
Due Thursday 2 March 2023, 11:59PM
Introduction
Can living in corrupt environments lead to an individual themselves perpetuating corrupt
behavior? Many scholars from different disciplines argue that this is the case anecdotally; critics
rightfully point out that such extrapolation usually reeks of confirmation bias at best and
discriminatory attitudes at worst. The problem, of course, is violations of the zero conditional
mean assumption – there are omitted variables and reverse causality issues that make
comparisons of behavior in more and less corrupt regions difficult to interpret causally.
This week, you’ll be using data from Raymond Fisman and Ted Miguel on parking violations by
UN diplomats, from a 2007 paper using these data titled, “Corruption, norms, and legal
enforcement: Evidence from diplomatic parking tickets.” The data file (UN parking.Rdata)
contains information on diplomatic parking violations in New York City between 1998 and 2005.
Most important, these data span a change in enforcement policy – after 2002, NYC began
enforcing payment for fines. This creates a so-called ‘natural experiment’ that helps turn what is
fundamentally a correlation story into one that looks more causal. You will want to start by
reading the introduction of the paper (Sections I and II) as an example of a very clear exposition
of motivation and background.
1 The Basics (20pts)
Create a new script (.R file) (“FamilyName PID HW3.R” – e.g., “Burney 12345678 HW3.R”).
Your script must generate all of the answers and graphics used in your written submission and
needs to run on its own, fully, without errors, to get full credit. We will cover exactly how to do
this in lab.
• Your script (.R file) is named correctly and runs without errors. You can assume that we
will run your script in a directory that has copies of the data files in the same directory, so
prior to submission, please comment out any code that points to your directory
structure.(10pts)
• Your script (.R file) does not overwrite the original data; it does the requisite analysis, and
outputs any figures or tables used in your writeup (labeled correctly, and saved with
filenames that include your family name and PID). Your script should start by loading any
necessary packages, and loading the data UN parking.Rdata. (10pts)
1
2 Theory and Background (20pts)
a Why do New York City parking tickets provide a good context for understanding the role of
norms in corruption? Why is important that this study spans the enforcement change, in terms
of understanding causality? Use the paper as a reference but be very careful to write this in
your own words – practice your academic integrity here! (1 paragraph; 5pts)
b Give two very concrete explanations/examples for why a study comparing parking violations of
diplomats in their own countries would not be as compelling. (1 paragraph; 5pts)
c Replicate Figure 1 in the paper using your data (it does not have to be exact, but it should give
the essence). Write a concise and compelling caption that explains what your figure shows and
why it matters in the context of your analysis. This is great practice for your independent
project! (1 figure with caption; 5pts)
d Provide a chart or table showing the top 5 and bottom 5 countries’ total number of unpaid
violations, before and after the enforcement change. As above, write a concise and compelling
caption that explains what your figure shows and why it matters in the context of your
analysis. (1 figure with caption; 5pts)
3 Data Preparation and Regression Analysis (40pts)
a Get your data into a format such that you have number of violations per country, before and
after the enforcement change (call the total variable violations). Make sure to keep the country
code as a variable. Now merge in the country data (CountryData.Rdata) and produce a
scatterplot that shows the relationship between total number of violations (y) and corruption
index (x). What is the hypothesis being tested here (in the theoretical sense; don’t just say
that x affects y)? (5pts)
b Run the simple regression of violations on the 1998 corruption index, corruption (use all of the
data). Store the estimate to include in your table later. What do you find? What are some
limitations of this simple model? (2-3 sentences; 5pts)
c Now include the timeperiod variable as a covariate in your regression. (Store the results.) What
is this regression telling you? (2-3 sentences; 5pts)
d Now include the full interaction of timeperiod and corruption. Store this estimate for your
table. What do you learn here? Interpret with one nice interaction figure and a concise caption.
(1 figure with caption; 5pts)
e From here through the rest of this section, restrict yourself to the pre-enforcement period. Now
regress violations on the full interaction of economic aid ecaid and corruption. Store this
estimate for your table. What do you learn here? Interpret with one nice interaction figure and
a concise caption. (1 figure with caption; 10pts)
f Finally, regress violations on the full interaction of region and corruption. Store this estimate
for your table. What do you learn here? Interpret with one nice interaction figure and a concise
caption. (1 figure with caption; 10pts)
2
4 Outlier Analysis and Threats to Validity (15pts)
Conduct a thorough analysis of potential outliers on the model in question 3 part d above.
Present your results clearly and concisely. If there are especially troubling data points, explain
what they are and explain how including or omitting them changes your results. (10pts) In
addition, what are some other limitations to your analysis? Are there omitted variables or other
problems with the research as conducted? How would you make it better? (5pts)
5 Final Regression Table (5pts)
Present one nicely formatted final regression table that contains the five regression results you
stored in Section 3b-f, and is clearly labeled. In your answers above, you can reference the table
by column, since the columns are the different model results.
3
The Basics (20pts)
Theory and Background (20pts)
Data Preparation and Regression Analysis (40pts)
Outlier Analysis and Threats to Validity (15pts)
Final Regression Table (5pts)
UN_Parking.Rdata
UN_Parking.Rdata
__MACOSX/._UN_Parking.Rdata
Answers
0
No answers posted
Post your Answer - free or at a fee
Ask a question for free and get answers to get R assignment help with a similar task to this question.